What Happens After the U.S. Economy’s Soft Landing?

Raw Text

Navigation Menu

Subscribe

Sign In

Account Menu Account Menu Hi,  Guest

Search Menu

Close menu

CLEAR

SUGGESTED TOPICS

Explore HBR

Latest

The Magazine

Ascend

Podcasts

Video

Store

Webinars

Newsletters

Popular Topics

Managing Yourself

Leadership

Strategy

Managing Teams

Gender

Innovation

Work-life Balance

All Topics

For Subscribers

The Big Idea

Data & Visuals

Reading Lists

Case Selections

HBR Learning

Subscribe

My Account

My Library

Topic Feeds

Orders

Account Settings

Email Preferences

Log Out

Sign In

Subscribe

Latest

Podcasts

Video

The Magazine

Ascend

Store

Webinars

Newsletters

All Topics

The Big Idea

Data & Visuals

Reading Lists

Case Selections

HBR Learning

My Library

Account Settings

Log Out

Sign In

Your Cart

Visit Our Store

My Library

Topic Feeds

Orders

Account Settings

Email Preferences

Log Out

Reading Lists

1 free

s

last free article

Subscribe

Create an account

Economic cycles and trends

by

Philipp Carlsson-Szlezak,

Paul Swartz,

and

Martin Reeves

by

Philipp Carlsson-Szlezak,

Paul Swartz,

and

Martin Reeves

baona/Getty Images

Tweet

Post

Share

Annotate

Save

Get PDF

Buy Copies

Print

Summary.

A year ago, a recession was seen as a foregone conclusion — and yet the Fed appears to have successfully lowered inflation without triggering a recession. Many of the negative forecasts followed a pattern of underestimating the U.S. economy’s resilience, typically because they were based on historical models and precedent, not situational and idiosyncratic context. While the soft landing may be progressing with promise, it won’t be an end state — a new disequilibrium will emerge. Leaders can’t wait for macroeconomic certainty or stability. Instead, they must recognize that the macroeconomy will remain untamed by models — and that what matters is judgment.

Tweet

Post

Share

Annotate

Save

Get PDF

Buy Copies

Print

Leer en espanol

Ler em portugues

The U.S. economy has defied the doomsayers once again. More than a year has passed since a recession was seen as a foregone conclusion and a “soft landing” pronounced near impossible. But today, the soft landing is well advanced, even if not complete: The Fed has found success in lowering inflation without triggering a recession. The labor market, the only reliable evidence that the economy is in recession, has cooled without pushing up the unemployment rate.

Though this is welcome news, the protracted uncertainty surrounding the economy has confounded many leaders — and came at a cost for those who hunkered down prematurely in anticipation of recession. This uncertainty will persist. What comes after the soft landing (if in fact it can be completed)? To answer this question, we look at why the recession calls were wrong and what lies ahead.

Recession Prophecies, Unfulfilled

As in the pandemic, when doomsayers predicted a “ Greater Depression ,” much negativity dominated public discourse of the last year and a half. Some leaders predicted a “ hurricane ” would hit the economy shortly; others dismissed even the possibility of a soft landing.

But as the below graphic illustrates, that is exactly what has played out over the last 16 months. Job openings have come off their highs as firms feel under less strain, and quit rates have fallen as workers feel less enticed to jump ship — all while hiring (“payrolls”) continues at a robust pace. As the unemployment rate remains near its 60-year low there is no sign of recession.

See more HBR charts in Data & Visuals

What went wrong, or, more appropriately, what went right?

Many of the negative forecasts followed a pattern of underestimating the U.S. economy’s resilience, typically because they were based on historical models and precedent – not situational and idiosyncratic context. Consider the following four displays of resilience:

Labor market resilience. The widespread assumption was that monetary policy would push labor demand collectively under water. Instead we have seen pockets of weakness, covered by aggregate strength. Significant layoffs happened where hiring had overshot (e.g., tech) but in other sectors (e.g., services) hiring was still catching up and remained strong. Laid-off workers found new jobs. Resilience was found in the unusual economic diversification of recessionary sectors with booming ones.

Consumer resilience. Growing layoffs, inflation eating away at household budgets, and falling portfolios weakening balance sheets led to predictions of a collapse in spending. But the context mattered. Balance sheets had buffers, including cash. And while individual budgets were squeezed, the total number of incomes continued to grow rapidly as hiring persisted, providing consumer strength. The aggregate downdraft has not happened.

Housing resilience. A common fear has been that rising interest rates would kneecap the housing market — delaying construction activity, pushing down prices, or even, as some doomsayers predicted, causing another housing-centered recession. But these narratives overlooked the fact that activity remains precisely because housing inventory is low . As a result, higher rates have tamped down — rather than choked — housing activity. Housing starts and prices dipped, and transactions fell, but they have stabilized and are rising again.

Financial system resilience. Another common fear was that the Fed will hike until something breaks. The idea that the financial system would be the collateral damage of higher rates is not unreasonable as the collapse of SVB demonstrated . But the risk of contagion was overestimated, while the ability of policy-makers to avert it was underestimated.

The better-than-expected outcomes share a pattern. Each concern had merit but was considered too narrowly. The idiosyncratic, contextual, and situational drivers mattered more than what historical relationships — and the models that are based on them — said about these sectors.

A lesson that cannot be learned often enough, it seems, is that trust in macroeconomic models remains too strong. The idiosyncrasies of the cycle call for judgment rather than precise forecasts. Meanwhile, the doomsaying is routinely amplified as the microphone is reliably passed to the gloomiest voices.

The Path Ahead

Economics often unhelpfully frames the economic cycle as “moving to equilibrium.” (The aviation analogy of a “soft landing” is similarly guilty.) In reality, we are always moving from one idiosyncratic disequilibrium to another, meaning executives cannot rely on forecasts . New idiosyncratic drivers will always deliver new situations that models won’t readily pick up on.

So, what could the new disequilibrium be?

Though the first stages of the soft landing are a success, ruling out a recession would be a mistake. It remains a possible, even plausible, outcome (and over time an inevitability). Monetary policy still has a foot on the brake. Real shocks can always end a cycle, particularly when growth is already slow and the economy thus more vulnerable, and financial stressors, such as bank failures, can pop up unexpectedly. Considering the three types of recession risk remains indispensable, but we still view recession risk in the near term as much lower than consensus.

A re-acceleration is more likely, as a resilient economy successfully weathers this period of weak (but non-recessionary) growth. Yet, such a re-acceleration could play out in different ways – some are welcome, others are not.

Scenario 1: A Re-run of the Overshooting Economy

If demand picks up strongly and outstrips the economy’s capacity (think available labor, capital, and known processes), another bout of inflation is likely. This would necessitate a fresh round of monetary tightening with all the risks we discussed above.

Even so, it would not immediately point to an “inflation regime break” — the mistaken narrative of the last two years that the U.S. economy was seeing a structural return of inflation. It would mean another bout of cyclical inflation that comes (and goes) with a mismatch of demand and supply.

Scenario 2: A Just-Right Economy

If demand grows in line with the economy’s capacity, the expansion can plod along at acceptable growth rates without renewed inflation pressures. Monetary policy could ease from its very tight stance toward a more neutral stance — until a shift toward a new disequilibrium arises.

Scenario 3: A Better-Than-Good Economy

We know this has arrived when the economy’s capacity grows considerably faster than demand, facilitating rapid growth without concomitant cyclical inflation. While strong capital formation and strong labor participation can help facilitate this scenario to a degree, it’s crux would be an acceleration of productivity growth.

Can this happen and is it likely?

Many are eager to pencil in much higher growth courtesy of ChatGPT and other applications of AI — but not so fast. The mere availability of technology does not guarantee faster productivity growth; think of tech as just the fuel . The spark typically comes in the form of tight labor markets. When firms are forced to substitute capital for labor, they tend to do more of it. When they can’t hire the next worker, they transform their processes.

Such sustained labor market tightness and its benefits are a realistic prospect. Still, leaders should remain prudent about size and speed of such gains. Big productivity gains at the macroeconomic level come gradually, not abruptly, and their size is often overestimated — as we saw in the pandemic, when analysts rushed to pencil in an extra 1 percentage point of growth that did not materialize.

The benefits of such a scenario would be broader than just somewhat higher growth. Tight labor markets create real wage growth across the income distribution, and the biggest winners tend to be at the bottom of the distribution. This creates opportunities for career advancement and job creation for those who have had fewer opportunities or struggled to get on the job ladder, and it pulls into the labor market those who may have otherwise exited.

. . .

While the soft landing may be progressing with promise, it won’t be an end state — a new disequilibrium will emerge. Leaders can’t wait for macroeconomic certainty or stability. Instead, they must recognize that the macroeconomy will remain untamed by models — and that what matters is judgment. Gloomy headlines will persist, and economic models will offer a flat view of the world that misses out on critical context. Leaders must apply the same skills they employ each day to lead their firms through uncertainty to navigating the macroeconomy. They must avoid both overreacting to the latest piece of data and preparing for only one unchanging view the future.

For firms, the challenges of a tight economy , including margin pressure, as well as higher, but healthy interest rates , are likely here to stay — but they are preferable to the alternative of recession. Meeting these challenges head on means more capital for labor substitution, more reinvention, and more technological absorption. Each of these form the foundation of the better-than-good economic scenario.

Read more on Economic cycles and trends or related topics Economics , Government policy and regulation , Recessions and Inflation

PC Philipp Carlsson-Szlezak is a partner and managing director in BCG’s New York office and global chief economist of BCG. He can be reached at: Carlsson-Szlezak.Philipp@bcg.com .

PS Paul Swartz is a director and senior economist in the BCG Henderson Institute, based in BCG’s New York office.

Martin Reeves is the chairman of Boston Consulting Group’s BCG Henderson Institute in San Francisco and a coauthor of The Imagination Machine (Harvard Business Review Press, 2021).

Tweet

Post

Share

Annotate

Save

Get PDF

Buy Copies

Print

Read more on Economic cycles and trends or related topics Economics , Government policy and regulation , Recessions and Inflation

Partner Center

Latest

Magazine

Ascend

Topics

Podcasts

Video

Store

The Big Idea

Data & Visuals

Case Selections

HBR Learning

Subscribe

Explore HBR

The Latest

All Topics

Magazine Archive

The Big Idea

Reading Lists

Case Selections

Video

Podcasts

Webinars

Data & Visuals

My Library

Newsletters

HBR Press

HBR Ascend

HBR Store

Article Reprints

Books

Cases

Collections

Magazine Issues

HBR Guide Series

HBR 20-Minute Managers

HBR Emotional Intelligence Series

HBR Must Reads

Tools

About HBR

Contact Us

Advertise with Us

Information for Booksellers/Retailers

Masthead

Global Editions

Media Inquiries

Guidelines for Authors

HBR Analytic Services

Copyright Permissions

Manage My Account

My Library

Topic Feeds

Orders

Account Settings

Email Preferences

Account FAQ

Help Center

Contact Customer Service

Follow HBR

Facebook

Twitter

LinkedIn

Instagram

Your Newsreader

About Us

Careers

Privacy Policy

Cookie Policy

Copyright Information

Trademark Policy

Higher Education

Corporate Learning

Harvard Business Review

Harvard Business School

Single Line Text

Navigation Menu. Subscribe. Sign In. Account Menu Account Menu Hi,  Guest. Search Menu. Close menu. CLEAR. SUGGESTED TOPICS. Explore HBR. Latest. The Magazine. Ascend. Podcasts. Video. Store. Webinars. Newsletters. Popular Topics. Managing Yourself. Leadership. Strategy. Managing Teams. Gender. Innovation. Work-life Balance. All Topics. For Subscribers. The Big Idea. Data & Visuals. Reading Lists. Case Selections. HBR Learning. Subscribe. My Account. My Library. Topic Feeds. Orders. Account Settings. Email Preferences. Log Out. Sign In. Subscribe. Latest. Podcasts. Video. The Magazine. Ascend. Store. Webinars. Newsletters. All Topics. The Big Idea. Data & Visuals. Reading Lists. Case Selections. HBR Learning. My Library. Account Settings. Log Out. Sign In. Your Cart. Visit Our Store. My Library. Topic Feeds. Orders. Account Settings. Email Preferences. Log Out. Reading Lists. 1 free. s. last free article. Subscribe. Create an account. Economic cycles and trends. by. Philipp Carlsson-Szlezak, Paul Swartz, and. Martin Reeves. by. Philipp Carlsson-Szlezak, Paul Swartz, and. Martin Reeves. baona/Getty Images. Tweet. Post. Share. Annotate. Save. Get PDF. Buy Copies. Print. Summary. A year ago, a recession was seen as a foregone conclusion — and yet the Fed appears to have successfully lowered inflation without triggering a recession. Many of the negative forecasts followed a pattern of underestimating the U.S. economy’s resilience, typically because they were based on historical models and precedent, not situational and idiosyncratic context. While the soft landing may be progressing with promise, it won’t be an end state — a new disequilibrium will emerge. Leaders can’t wait for macroeconomic certainty or stability. Instead, they must recognize that the macroeconomy will remain untamed by models — and that what matters is judgment. Tweet. Post. Share. Annotate. Save. Get PDF. Buy Copies. Print. Leer en espanol. Ler em portugues. The U.S. economy has defied the doomsayers once again. More than a year has passed since a recession was seen as a foregone conclusion and a “soft landing” pronounced near impossible. But today, the soft landing is well advanced, even if not complete: The Fed has found success in lowering inflation without triggering a recession. The labor market, the only reliable evidence that the economy is in recession, has cooled without pushing up the unemployment rate. Though this is welcome news, the protracted uncertainty surrounding the economy has confounded many leaders — and came at a cost for those who hunkered down prematurely in anticipation of recession. This uncertainty will persist. What comes after the soft landing (if in fact it can be completed)? To answer this question, we look at why the recession calls were wrong and what lies ahead. Recession Prophecies, Unfulfilled. As in the pandemic, when doomsayers predicted a “ Greater Depression ,” much negativity dominated public discourse of the last year and a half. Some leaders predicted a “ hurricane ” would hit the economy shortly; others dismissed even the possibility of a soft landing. But as the below graphic illustrates, that is exactly what has played out over the last 16 months. Job openings have come off their highs as firms feel under less strain, and quit rates have fallen as workers feel less enticed to jump ship — all while hiring (“payrolls”) continues at a robust pace. As the unemployment rate remains near its 60-year low there is no sign of recession. See more HBR charts in Data & Visuals. What went wrong, or, more appropriately, what went right? Many of the negative forecasts followed a pattern of underestimating the U.S. economy’s resilience, typically because they were based on historical models and precedent – not situational and idiosyncratic context. Consider the following four displays of resilience: Labor market resilience. The widespread assumption was that monetary policy would push labor demand collectively under water. Instead we have seen pockets of weakness, covered by aggregate strength. Significant layoffs happened where hiring had overshot (e.g., tech) but in other sectors (e.g., services) hiring was still catching up and remained strong. Laid-off workers found new jobs. Resilience was found in the unusual economic diversification of recessionary sectors with booming ones. Consumer resilience. Growing layoffs, inflation eating away at household budgets, and falling portfolios weakening balance sheets led to predictions of a collapse in spending. But the context mattered. Balance sheets had buffers, including cash. And while individual budgets were squeezed, the total number of incomes continued to grow rapidly as hiring persisted, providing consumer strength. The aggregate downdraft has not happened. Housing resilience. A common fear has been that rising interest rates would kneecap the housing market — delaying construction activity, pushing down prices, or even, as some doomsayers predicted, causing another housing-centered recession. But these narratives overlooked the fact that activity remains precisely because housing inventory is low . As a result, higher rates have tamped down — rather than choked — housing activity. Housing starts and prices dipped, and transactions fell, but they have stabilized and are rising again. Financial system resilience. Another common fear was that the Fed will hike until something breaks. The idea that the financial system would be the collateral damage of higher rates is not unreasonable as the collapse of SVB demonstrated . But the risk of contagion was overestimated, while the ability of policy-makers to avert it was underestimated. The better-than-expected outcomes share a pattern. Each concern had merit but was considered too narrowly. The idiosyncratic, contextual, and situational drivers mattered more than what historical relationships — and the models that are based on them — said about these sectors. A lesson that cannot be learned often enough, it seems, is that trust in macroeconomic models remains too strong. The idiosyncrasies of the cycle call for judgment rather than precise forecasts. Meanwhile, the doomsaying is routinely amplified as the microphone is reliably passed to the gloomiest voices. The Path Ahead. Economics often unhelpfully frames the economic cycle as “moving to equilibrium.” (The aviation analogy of a “soft landing” is similarly guilty.) In reality, we are always moving from one idiosyncratic disequilibrium to another, meaning executives cannot rely on forecasts . New idiosyncratic drivers will always deliver new situations that models won’t readily pick up on. So, what could the new disequilibrium be? Though the first stages of the soft landing are a success, ruling out a recession would be a mistake. It remains a possible, even plausible, outcome (and over time an inevitability). Monetary policy still has a foot on the brake. Real shocks can always end a cycle, particularly when growth is already slow and the economy thus more vulnerable, and financial stressors, such as bank failures, can pop up unexpectedly. Considering the three types of recession risk remains indispensable, but we still view recession risk in the near term as much lower than consensus. A re-acceleration is more likely, as a resilient economy successfully weathers this period of weak (but non-recessionary) growth. Yet, such a re-acceleration could play out in different ways – some are welcome, others are not. Scenario 1: A Re-run of the Overshooting Economy. If demand picks up strongly and outstrips the economy’s capacity (think available labor, capital, and known processes), another bout of inflation is likely. This would necessitate a fresh round of monetary tightening with all the risks we discussed above. Even so, it would not immediately point to an “inflation regime break” — the mistaken narrative of the last two years that the U.S. economy was seeing a structural return of inflation. It would mean another bout of cyclical inflation that comes (and goes) with a mismatch of demand and supply. Scenario 2: A Just-Right Economy. If demand grows in line with the economy’s capacity, the expansion can plod along at acceptable growth rates without renewed inflation pressures. Monetary policy could ease from its very tight stance toward a more neutral stance — until a shift toward a new disequilibrium arises. Scenario 3: A Better-Than-Good Economy. We know this has arrived when the economy’s capacity grows considerably faster than demand, facilitating rapid growth without concomitant cyclical inflation. While strong capital formation and strong labor participation can help facilitate this scenario to a degree, it’s crux would be an acceleration of productivity growth. Can this happen and is it likely? Many are eager to pencil in much higher growth courtesy of ChatGPT and other applications of AI — but not so fast. The mere availability of technology does not guarantee faster productivity growth; think of tech as just the fuel . The spark typically comes in the form of tight labor markets. When firms are forced to substitute capital for labor, they tend to do more of it. When they can’t hire the next worker, they transform their processes. Such sustained labor market tightness and its benefits are a realistic prospect. Still, leaders should remain prudent about size and speed of such gains. Big productivity gains at the macroeconomic level come gradually, not abruptly, and their size is often overestimated — as we saw in the pandemic, when analysts rushed to pencil in an extra 1 percentage point of growth that did not materialize. The benefits of such a scenario would be broader than just somewhat higher growth. Tight labor markets create real wage growth across the income distribution, and the biggest winners tend to be at the bottom of the distribution. This creates opportunities for career advancement and job creation for those who have had fewer opportunities or struggled to get on the job ladder, and it pulls into the labor market those who may have otherwise exited. . . . While the soft landing may be progressing with promise, it won’t be an end state — a new disequilibrium will emerge. Leaders can’t wait for macroeconomic certainty or stability. Instead, they must recognize that the macroeconomy will remain untamed by models — and that what matters is judgment. Gloomy headlines will persist, and economic models will offer a flat view of the world that misses out on critical context. Leaders must apply the same skills they employ each day to lead their firms through uncertainty to navigating the macroeconomy. They must avoid both overreacting to the latest piece of data and preparing for only one unchanging view the future. For firms, the challenges of a tight economy , including margin pressure, as well as higher, but healthy interest rates , are likely here to stay — but they are preferable to the alternative of recession. Meeting these challenges head on means more capital for labor substitution, more reinvention, and more technological absorption. Each of these form the foundation of the better-than-good economic scenario. Read more on Economic cycles and trends or related topics Economics , Government policy and regulation , Recessions and Inflation. PC Philipp Carlsson-Szlezak is a partner and managing director in BCG’s New York office and global chief economist of BCG. He can be reached at: Carlsson-Szlezak.Philipp@bcg.com . PS Paul Swartz is a director and senior economist in the BCG Henderson Institute, based in BCG’s New York office. Martin Reeves is the chairman of Boston Consulting Group’s BCG Henderson Institute in San Francisco and a coauthor of The Imagination Machine (Harvard Business Review Press, 2021). Tweet. Post. Share. Annotate. Save. Get PDF. Buy Copies. Print. Read more on Economic cycles and trends or related topics Economics , Government policy and regulation , Recessions and Inflation. Partner Center. Latest. Magazine. Ascend. Topics. Podcasts. Video. Store. The Big Idea. Data & Visuals. Case Selections. HBR Learning. Subscribe. Explore HBR. The Latest. All Topics. Magazine Archive. The Big Idea. Reading Lists. Case Selections. Video. Podcasts. Webinars. Data & Visuals. My Library. Newsletters. HBR Press. HBR Ascend. HBR Store. Article Reprints. Books. Cases. Collections. Magazine Issues. HBR Guide Series. HBR 20-Minute Managers. HBR Emotional Intelligence Series. HBR Must Reads. Tools. About HBR. Contact Us. Advertise with Us. Information for Booksellers/Retailers. Masthead. Global Editions. Media Inquiries. Guidelines for Authors. HBR Analytic Services. Copyright Permissions. Manage My Account. My Library. Topic Feeds. Orders. Account Settings. Email Preferences. Account FAQ. Help Center. Contact Customer Service. Follow HBR. Facebook. Twitter. LinkedIn. Instagram. Your Newsreader. About Us. Careers. Privacy Policy. Cookie Policy. Copyright Information. Trademark Policy. Higher Education. Corporate Learning. Harvard Business Review. Harvard Business School.